Is the European Union heading for a Soviet-style
collapse?
“Evils which are patiently endured when they seem inevitable, become
intolerable once the idea of escape from them is suggested.”
—Alexis de
Tocqueville, The Old Regime
and the Revolution
Is the European Union headed for the kind of collapse
that would make it this decade’s Soviet Union? Tocqueville famously observed
that the collapse of political institutions usually seems inconceivable, right
up until the moment it happens—at which point the collapse is seen to have been
inevitable and over-determined by the underlying corrosive trends that were
pulling the institution apart.
This mismatch of perception
with reality is more than just a function of the threshold collective action
dilemma that confronts revolutionary movements.1 It is a cognitive and emotional dilemma that
faces pundits and politicians too: To admit institutional fragility is
sometimes tantamount to encouraging fracture. And when a political institution
has deep emotional roots in the collective psyche of a population—whether those
roots are more about love or resentment or even hate—it is hard to imagine a
scenario in which the institution has disappeared and the world must figure out
how to go on without it.
So it was with the USSR a
generation ago. In 1988, the Soviet Union was widely judged, both inside and
outside the country, to be troubled but stable. On January 1, 1992 it ceased to
exist. American Sovietologists spent much of the next decade trying to figure
out why they couldn’t see in advance what, in retrospect, appeared to be
inevitable.
In 2016 the European Union is
certainly challenged and troubled. But will it collapse, or is it stable enough
to survive? The evidence of the past few years—Grexit averted and the euro
rescued (at least for the time being)—could suggest “yes.” One could even take
it as a signal of underlying EU strength. The summer 2016 Brexit vote might be,
when all is said and done, a disastrous choice for Britain and a spur to EU
reform that will strengthen and make more resilient what remains.
That’s a
hopeful perspective for Europhiles, but we believe it is wrong. The historical
parallels between the European Union of 2016 and the USSR circa 1989 are deep
enough to take seriously. And in an ironic twist of intellectual history,
American scholarship on the European Union is in the grip of a mirror image of
the prejudicial tendencies of theory that afflicted Sovietologists in the
1980s.
The similarities fall into
three key elements of political economy. The political component of the
European Union is broken in a manner eerily similar to that of the late-stage
Soviet Union. Both were curiously apolitical, because they sat on
elite-driven teleological foundations that ignore how human beings actually
live and bargain. The economic component is broken in parallel: Both were tied
to peculiar and incoherent ideologies that respond to economic stagnation by
getting even more confused, making major policy mistakes all but
inevitable.
But the most important
similarity lies in the dynamic that turned the late Soviet experiment of
perestroika (“restructuring”) and, later, glasnost (“openness”) into a
cascading institutional failure. Because of its history and organizational
configuration, the European Union may be structurally un-reformable in many of
the same ways that Soviet Russia was, as Gorbachev discovered to his surprise.
If that is right, then the
most likely path forward will witness the emergence in the European Union of a
Gorbachev-type figure who makes the explicit case that muddling through is not
enough. This leader will begin by trying to restructure the Brussels
bureaucracy, but will find herself with no choice but to radically re-think the
European Union’s democratic deficit. She will then watch helplessly as the EU
edifice cracks and crumbles, and will know exactly how Gorbachev felt around
1989. And when it’s over, Americans will once again be found asking themselves,
“why didn’t we see it coming?”
We do not advocate for the end
of the European Union. Its flaws and foibles notwithstanding, we recognize and
honor the extraordinary historical achievements of the world’s most elaborate
and sophisticated experiment in supranational governance. But we need to call
it like we see it, not how we might wish it to be.
Politics
Not long after the Brexit vote shocked the world,
Martin Wolf wrote in the Financial Times that the European
Union should be a “refuge not a prison.” He meant that,
the core challenge of the EU is to make it work—and be seen to work—for the
benefit of the great majority of its citizens…. The failure of the EU lies not
in its political structures but in its policies. It must secure legitimacy via
practical achievements rather than further erosion of national autonomy.2
The world’s premier economic columnist here named, perhaps without quite
knowing it, the central contradiction at the heart of the European Union.
To make this concrete,
consider the policy response that Wolf (along with many other respected
economists) argues is necessary for Europe to rebound out of its
post-global-financial-crisis slump and avoid future Greek-style crises. If you
believed that the appropriate policy response was a combination of fiscal stimulus
and a rebalancing of the zone’s macroeconomic rules so that they less blatantly
favor the Union’s largest and richest country (Germany), then the obvious next
question is: why didn’t that happen?
The fundamental answer lies
neither in some abstract ideology of austerity wafting through the conference
rooms of the European Central Bank nor in some putative Teutonic commitment to
discipline debtors no matter the ultimate cost. It lies in a much simpler
institutional fact: The European Union remains a monetary union but not a
fiscal union. The only way today’s European Union could reasonably produce the
policies Wolf and many others advocate is if it were at least a de facto fiscal
union. But that would require radical reform of the political structure of the
Union.
In other words, it is EU political structures themselves that
are ultimately at fault for the European Union’s economic policy mistakes.
But the real contradiction
resides at a level deeper. It is right to say that the European Union, like all
political systems, must ultimately secure legitimacy through practical
achievements. But it can’t do that without changing political structures that
fail systematically to produce needed policies. And it can’t change those
political structures without further eroding national autonomy—a prospect for
which there is little meaningful popular support, since such a move would be
seen (with justification) as a further erosion of democratic accountability.
The irony of European
integration is that engendering these contradictions was the plan all
along. Jean Monnet and his successors weren’t naive dreamers; they
understood that nationalism would remain strong in Europe despite its largely
having caused two disastrous world wars. So how could European integration then
proceed “beyond the nation-state,” as Ernest Haas put it in his classic 1964
book of that title?
The logic of integration,
labeled “neo-functionalism” by Haas, was based on technocratic notions of how
governance requirements among economically interdependent states would evolve.
The model was supposed to work like this: A European elite would identify a
policy objective that would be presented to the European public as a positive
incremental step in the direction of economic integration. This would create
“spillover effects” in the form of a perceived need to follow up with further
integrative moves in order to stabilize and capture the promised economic
benefits. Rather than mounting a frontal assault on national sovereignty, the
reason to “go further” would be simply to complete the logic inherent in the
previous steps, embodied in concrete economic incentives to finish what had
been started.
Essentially every economist
who looked at the creation of the monetary union and the euro remarked on the
inherent instability of a large and diverse currency union that was not also a
fiscal union. In 1997, before the euro’s launch, Milton Friedman famously
predicted that the new currency
would not survive the Eurozone’s first economic downturn.3 But from the point of view of the Eurozone’s
architects, this risk structure was exactly the point: technocratic creation of
facts on the ground in one domain (monetary union) would drive a perceived need
to go further down the integration pathway (toward fiscal union), which would
in turn drive political integration. To mix technological metaphors: putting
the monetary cart before the political horse was a feature, not a bug.
The more ambitious
neo-functionalists believed that, over time, the multiplying intensity of
cross-border transactions and the “necessary” transfer of regulatory authority
to supranational institutions would generate a European identity to sit
alongside and eventually supplant national identities. But in typically
technocratic fashion, even that transfer of allegiance didn’t depend on
confronting directly the ideological foundations of nationalist feeling.
Instead, it would come about gradually, almost under the radar, via mundane
institutional development—as interest groups, industry associations, and the
like within individual countries reorganized along European lines.
Technocratic incrementalism,
economic rationality, supranational governance to capture the benefits of a
globalizing world—these were supposed to be the driving forces behind European
institutional integration. Neo-functionalism was a way of sidestepping politics
and hoping that it would follow along without too much disruption.
Unfortunately, what was once a
brilliant political strategy has now become Europe’s Achilles’ heel. In
retrospect, what is surprising is how far the neo-functionalist dynamic took
Europe before hitting its limits. But it’s been faltering now for some time.
When the Solemn Declaration on European Union in 1983 declared that the goal
was “commitment to progress toward an ever closer union” based on social
democracy, cosmopolitanism, and human rights, it was already starting to sound
tired to a younger generation of Europeans who felt that the continent was
falling behind the globalization curve. Strong economic performance can hide
institutional failure for a while, but not forever.
Consider 1992, when the French
referendum on the Maastricht Treaty squeaked through with 51.1 percent and
later was rejected in Denmark by a similar margin. Denmark was then given a
series of opt-outs: no single currency, no common defense, no union
citizenship—and asked to vote again. In retrospect, these exceptions set an
ominous precedent: “ever-closer union” except, except, except. It also set a
precedent for do-over votes when referenda produced results unacceptable to the
technocratic plan. It happened in Ireland in 2008 with the Treaty of Amsterdam.
It happened in 2015 with the rejection of the Greek referendum, and the
response was to send back to Athens even harsher bailout terms for Syriza to
swallow.
The most important failures
here lie in Brussels’s systematic inability to grapple with the primacy of
politics. Neo-functionalism was an elegant idea, but that fifty year old theory
doesn’t describe how politics works in the 21st century. Magicians won’t show you the same trick
more than a few times for a reason: You’ll start to see the sleight of hand even
if you don’t want to. Once the shell shock of two world wars faded over
several generations, Europeans no longer wanted to trick themselves into
integration. They sought clear and conscious decisions, and they wanted openly
to debate the stakes of those decisions.
And so the creation of
“technocratic facts on the ground” is now more likely to promote resentment and
backpedalling when elites try to claim that the next politically delicate step
isn’t really political but somehow natural and inevitable—as a result of what
they themselves chose to do without sufficient public support or understanding
just a few years earlier. This is particularly galling to those who must live
in the “actually existing” EU, which (like the Soviet Union before it) has
failed to deliver the promised golden age of solidarity and prosperity.
Instead what a broad swathe of
Europeans see is that the European Union is a boon to bulge bracket bankers
(Central London is the richest place in Europe) and bureaucrats in Brussels
(the third-richest), and a politically unresponsive originator of regulation
for most everyone else. What we are witnessing is neo-functionalist dynamics
gone bad: more and more supranational regulation that hasn’t spilled over to
political responsiveness and integration.
This story may not look much like the Soviet Union on
the face of it, but there is a fundamental similarity that bodes ill for
Europe. The simple observation is that both the European Union and the Soviet
Union were built on teleological philosophies of history that posit an
inevitable endpoint toward which time and events must progress, and that
ignores how human beings really think and live.
In the Soviet case, it was the
inevitability of the coming of proletarian empowerment and international
solidarity. Hindsight makes it easy to scoff, but the USSR was supposed to have
been the epitome of modern political organization—a point affirmed by no less a
conservative authority than Samuel Huntington.4 The 1917 revolution was supposed to have ended
the need for further revolutions. The utopian impulse was ever-present in the
official ideology that would abolish private property and markets, and create
the “new Soviet Man.”
When these narratives faltered
(as they did in 1921, in the run-up to World War II, and ultimately in the
economic stagnation that set during the 1970s), the Party responded
pragmatically but soon did everything it could, ranging from propaganda to
Stalinist terror, to revive them. What began as a radiant myth slowly decayed
into a radioactive lie, or at least into a permanent condition of hypocrisy. By
the end of the Brezhnev era the teleology simply wasn’t plausible anymore, and
just about anyone living in Moscow in the early 1980s would have likely felt
that the arrow of history was pointing in precisely the opposite direction from
what the official narrative claimed. Even the most hardened apparatchiks of
that period and the succeeding administrations of Chernenko and Andropov knew
in their hearts it was a lie.5
And when the teleology went
out of it, all that was left was a stagnant and rigid bureaucracy cynically
extracting rents from an underperforming economy. Governments can survive this
kind of cynicism for a while, but not forever. Having an historic, heroic
ideology at that point becomes a burden rather than a boost, a constant
reminder of the failure of the regime to deliver. That’s why Napoleon, the pig
ruler of Animal Farm, had to scribble on top of “all animals are
equal” that “some animals are more equal than others.” His iron rule would have
been more stable if he had simply replaced the human farmer autocracy with his
own and never written the first part of that manifesto in the first place.
The truth is that nothing in
politics is inevitable. To pretend and act otherwise is a recipe for repression
or, in the case of the European Union, a populist backlash. It is no surprise
that so many of the Brexiteers saw an irreconcilable conflict between the elite
and everyone else (that irreconcilability being a distinctive,
defining feature of populism). Teleology is ultimately more like a religion
than a political belief system, and 21st-century Europe isn’t a place where any religion will
hold people together very long. (How this applies to depleted teleologies in
the United States is an interesting question too, but not for now.)
Economics
Robust economic growth is nature’s greatest political
salve. But no economy grows robustly forever. In periods of rapid economic
change, the test of a political economy’s stability is not so much how it
manages growth as how it manages volatility. In the late 20th and early 21st centuries, volatility has often taken the form
of rapid, sector-specific growth bursts interspersed among periods of
stagnation.
The second failure common to
both the European Union and the USSR is that both were built on ideological
foundations that responded to the challenges of economic stagnation when it
happened by getting more confused, not more cogent. Over time, the responsible
institutions became more rigid, not more flexible. Together these made
stagnation harder to live with for meaningful periods of time, and harder to
escape by means of enacting sometimes-necessary bold policy actions.
By the mid-1970s the Soviet
Union was mired in a vicious circle of declining economic productivity that
showed no signs or means of reversal.6 The Kremlin leadership may not have had a full
picture of just how stagnant the economy was, but to citizens and workers the
tangible evidence of daily experience was clear. The problem was that the
governing Soviet economic model—ultimately a set of ideas like all such
models—didn’t stand for anything that could compensate for lack of growth. It
certainly wasn’t about the rights and dignity of the proletariat, or
anti-colonialism, or even great power status—because it was no longer
contributing to any of those goals. It wasn’t clear what the Soviet economy
stood for, or why it deserved to exist.
By contrast, the other
superpower responded to its own 1970s economic stagnation with the supply-side
revolution. No matter where you stood on that set of ideas, there was no
question that it made a clear case for what needed to be done and what the
results would be. And it drove significant policy change, from painful monetary
tightening under Paul Volker to massive tax reduction and military
Keynesianism. By 1984 everyone knew where the U.S. economy was headed and what
it stood for: renewed growth through lower taxes, stable inflation,
deregulation, de-unionization, higher corporate profits – all in the name of
rebuilding the military in order to confront the Soviet Union. This vision was
exactly what Ronald Reagan was referring to when his signature reelection
campaign ad declared that it was “morning in America.”
The same clarity of purpose
has been present in the Chinese government and Communist Party leadership for
the last four decades. They exist in order to sustain a level of growth that
has lifted hundreds of millions of people out of poverty in just a few decades,
while gradually re-balancing the nature of that growth from export-led growth
at all costs to ecologically sustainable internal consumption, all the while
maintaining political and social stability as the CCP defines it. Love it or
hate it, there’s no ambiguity about that purpose, and a great deal of room for
policy flexibility in service of it.
By this standard, what does
today’s European Union stand for? In 2016 you might say that the EU’s purpose
in confronting economic stagnation is some ambiguous mixture of
post-nationalism, competitiveness, peace between historically warring states,
lesser inequality…or maybe something else. Nobody really knows anymore, and
that is a huge economic and political vulnerability.
Most Europeans experience
Brussels as a place of abstract pronouncements and convoluted institutional
processes that few can understand but that visibly generates more regulation
than economic growth. There is no greater purpose that compensates for this
experience by giving it meaning, and no blueprint that legitimates
institutional flexibility in the service of unconventional policy options.
The moral and political rot at
the heart of the Union came into sharp focus with the Greek debt crisis. For
ordinary Greeks, the crisis was one created by the corrupt cabal of plutocrats
and politicians, which they had just gotten done throwing out of office. Now
was the time, they believed, for pan-European solidarity—a bailout on
reasonable terms in exchange for a promise to clean up the books. Isn’t that
what European citizenship was supposed to mean: that we would all stand with
each other in times of trouble?
The Germans and many other
Northern Europeans of course took a very different view, namely that the
feckless and lazy Greeks needed to accept a major downside shock to their
standard of living and so learn some fiscal and labor discipline. In practice,
this meant imposing a stringent austerity program over the explicitly stated
political preferences of the local population.
One way or another, either the
democratic wishes of the Greeks or those of the Germans would have to be
defied. These are the moments that define polities. And in this instance, a
massive power imbalance combined with rigid rules and no greater sense of
shared purpose to ensure an official nightmare that perpetuates inequality
while multiplying perceptions of unfairness and illegitimacy.
The critical question is how
did the European Union end up stuck in this Kafka-by-way-of-Hobbes nightmare?
There are diverse explanations that run the gamut from the inherently
conservative tendencies of international organizations, to faulty leadership,
and more. But the explanation that matters most for the European Union’s future
prospects is its obsession with process. In Brussels, process trumps
everything. The system is paramount and the rules of process sacrosanct. It was
designed to be so in a manner that only technocratic institutions can be.
It’s as if the generation that
created the foundations of today’s European were, in the wake of World War II,
utterly frightened of meaning and purpose (which of course the Third Reich had
in spades) or any ideas that were abstract enough to catalyze political
emotion. So they substituted legal and bureaucratic processes that over time
became their own justification for existence yet, eventually, the European
Union’s stealth enemy from within. The problem is, there is scant political
constituency for process on its own—except possibly in the wake of purpose gone
bad. And that was several generations ago. The European Union desperately needs
a purpose beyond self-maintenance and survival, but its institutions are
designed almost to prevent such a purpose from emerging.
Change and
Stasis
Comparing today’s European Union with the late stage
Soviet Union is not an effort to ignore or mask very significant differences.
Europe is a much more prosperous place than was the Soviet Union, and that very
prosperity promotes a degree of conservatism about institutional change. The
Soviet Union had an external enemy, ideological and practical, to contend with
in the form of a hostile superpower. The European Union’s external challenge
just now is first and foremost about immigration and that is something that the
European Union still can, in principle, hope to manage more effectively than
can 28 (or possibly soon 27) individual national governments. The cultural milieu
could hardly be more different. And so on.
But amid these differences,
the parallel fragilities and rigidities of politics and economics point to the
single most important locus of comparison. When the late stage Soviet Union
under Gorbachev finally embarked on a serious program of reform, the system
cracked and ultimately collapsed. It didn’t take long. In a May 1985 speech in
Leningrad, Gorbachev openly acknowledged that the Soviet Union was suffering
from persistent, structural economic stagnation. The idea of perestroika
emerged later that same year. In 1987 Gorbachev presented his core policy plans
for economic restructuring to the Central Committee of the Communist Party. In
November 1989 the Berlin Wall came down, and just about three short years later,
the Soviet Union itself went out of existence. That’s seven years for one of
modern history’s most ambitious experiments in radical political organization
and governance to go the full spectrum from superpower status to dissolution.
At some point, the European
Union will have to embark on its own reform path. The critical question is
whether the European Union is in fact structurally un-reformable and destined
for collapse. A look back at the most compelling argument for why the Soviet
Union may have been so sheds some important light on that question.
In the winter of 1990, when Western optimism about
Gorbachev was nearly at its height, Berkeley historian Martin Malia wrote “To
the Stalin Mausoleum” in Daedalus under the pseudonym “Z.” On
the face of it, Malia argued, optimism about Gorbachev seemed easy to justify.
The Soviet Union finally had a leader who understood the roots of economic
stagnation and was willing to confront them, who understood the dysfunctions of
an empire in Eastern Europe and was eager to liberate it, who understood the
downside of the USSR’s isolation from a globalizing world economy and was ready
to integrate in a deliberate manner, and who understood the drain and danger of
an escalating nuclear arms race with the United States and was anxious to stop
it. What Malia saw instead were the deeper contradictions of the Soviet Union
that, he believed, made Gorbachev’s preferred reform path unworkable.
Those contradictions started
with the origins of the Soviet system in utopian ideologies, but in practice it
was the institutional consequences of reaching for utopia that doomed the
Soviet state. The 1917 narrative of the Great Proletarian Revolution covered up
a much more prosaic reality—“a minority coup d’etat staged
against a background of generalized, particularly peasant, anarchy,” as Malia
put it.
Jean Monnet was hardly Lenin,
but the mismatch of narrative and real policy in the 1951 Treaty of Paris was
similarly wide. European integration began with French Foreign Minister Robert
Schuman declaring on May 9, 1950, that the European Coal and Steel Community
(ECSC) was above all a means of making war “not only unthinkable but materially
impossible.” But its first institutions represented a much more prosaic effort
to create an integrated and managed market for steel and coal in order to deal
with overcapacity through a multi-government-run cartel.
Of course, stabilizing these
important sectors of both the French and German national markets by linking
their destinies together was the planned route to building a stable political
relationship between France and Germany. But the ECSC failed to prevent a
return of the large coal and steel firms to market power. Nor did it put
forward an energy policy at the intersection of the two “newer” fuels: oil and
nuclear. What it did achieve was the creation of a complex set of institutions
that were out of proportion to its objectives: A High Authority, a Common
Assembly, a Court of Justice, a Special Council of Ministers (with a
President), and a Consultative Committee made up of representatives from the
coal and steel markets. These institutions were the predecessors to today’s EU
bureaucratic labyrinth.
The Soviet Union faced its
greatest external challenge from the rise of Nazi Germany in the 1930s. It
first made a secret non-aggression pact to divert that challenge and buy time
for preparation. Ultimately, the sacrifice of moral coherence and authority
that the Molotov-von Ribbentrop pact represented was justified by the result of
the war, a decisive assertion of Soviet power in victory and a legitimating
narrative of great power and then superpower status that followed.
The European Union, in
contrast, has been a great-power-in-waiting for decades. The wars in the former
Republic of Yugoslavia during the late 1990s were its greatest external
challenge—and the European Union’s collective security response fell somewhere
between anemic and incoherent. Even worse, the excuses for inaction frequently
rested on process and institutional self-absorption, not intentional purpose.
The morally corrosive effects of that failure were exacerbated further by the
concentration camp parallels of Serbian ethnic cleansing on the European
continent, just four decades after the Holocaust. The European Union might be able
to prevent war, but what did that signify if it could not prevent the mass
murder that war brought in train and that constituted the main reason for
wanting to prevent it in the first place?
The failure to seize that
moment seemed to some observers to be the moral nadir of the European project.
In a triumph of technocratic process over meaning and purpose, the project to
engineer a single currency went forward while the effort to end genocide on the
continent was left to the Americans. Debates about optimal currency areas and
monetary policy arrangements crowded out what should have been a profound
period of soul-searching over the Yugoslav debacle. It was almost as if the
ghosts of the Soviet nomenklatura, whose bureaucratic triumph defined the Brezhnev
era in the Soviet Union, had silently returned to Brussels.
The fundamentals haven’t
changed much since then. When the 2008 financial crisis arrived, and the
entirely predictable crisis of the euro with it, the system stuck to a kind of
rump neo-functionalist logic as it forced the vast majority of adjustment costs
onto a destitute Greece. We say “rump neo-functonalist” because the logical
option for an integrationist alternative, moving toward fiscal union, was
patently obvious. But it was never even on the political table in a serious
way, at least not where it mattered (in Berlin and Paris).
In practice, the EU system
responded to crisis by putting its own institutional survival ahead of the
economic needs and political desires of its citizens. The corrosive loss of
legitimacy at this watershed moment is not the only way to explain the deep
roots of the Brexit vote, but it is surely part of what the Leavers saw and
felt. If Brexit was in part a vote against globalization, it was against
precisely the kind of globalization that EU institutions had fostered—with
benefits for the rich and mobile, a few structural funds to compensate many
losers, and no greater purpose than moving forward for its own sake.
Analytic Blind
Spots
Alongside his analysis of Soviet rigidity and
imperviousness to reform, Malia also offered a trenchant intellectual history
of late Western Sovietology, seeking to answer the question of why others
didn’t (and in fact couldn’t) see the breakup coming. In his view, most Western
scholars of the Soviet Union in the 1980s were focused on the sources of Soviet stability as
a mature industrial society facing gradual reform and increasingly pluralist
(not democratic) development.
Perhaps this was a reaction to
a previous generation’s totalitarian models that tended to paint the Soviet
Union as a unitary monolith of state power. Perhaps it was a side effect of
international relations’ theory of bipolarity, which suggested that the Cold
War was a meta-stable equilibrium that would continue indefinitely.7 Perhaps it was partly wishful thinking, with the
alternative (the break up of a major nuclear power) too unnerving to
contemplate. It certainly served the budgetary interests of the Pentagon to
have a stable, predictable, adaptive, and consistently hostile adversary
permanently ensconced on the other side of the Iron Curtain.
Are there similar blind spots
in American scholarship on the European Union? Possibly. In the international
relations world, the EU stands out as the most ambitious and interesting
experiment in supranational governance yet attempted. For many scholars,
particularly in the American academy, the European Union represents a beau
ideal of cosmopolitan governance, a model for the rest of the world.8 The transformation of historically warring
nation-states into a security community where war is unthinkable marks a
similar watershed; it testifies to the darling premise of liberal
institutionalists: rationality after all. The idea that flexible, adaptive
responses to the political economy of globalization can be engineered at the
scale of a continent is worthy of fascination. Observers disagree vehemently
over the mechanisms of European integration, some arguing that apparent
supra-national institutions are much more about normal bargaining between
national governments, much as you would see in the WTO or the United Nations.
But these arguments aside, stability is still the predominant concentration and
focus of explanation.
And so one is much more likely
to read justifications for why other regions (such as East Asia) should look to
the European Union as a model for the future than to read of reasons why the
European Union itself might be fundamentally unstable. It’s true that many
analyses of EU politics come with the discourse of “crisis” in the title or
subtitle. But this brand of crisis discourse is much like the thirty-year
“crisis” that has been facing NATO: a challenge to which the institution will
respond by moving forward and adapting. The possibility of an EU breakup isn’t
out of the picture, but it’s certainly in a fuzzy background that few observers
want to bring into clear focus.
Is Reform
Possible?
Nothing in politics is inevitable. Whatever impact it
may or may not have on the European economy, the Brexit vote was a massive psychological
shock to a system that never really imagined the possibility of
neo-functionalism slamming into reverse. Is it possible now to imagine a path
forward for European integration?
Of course it is. Here’s one
story that would represent a phoenix-like revival of post neo-functionalist
European integration. Elites in Germany and France take conscious, active
ownership of the partial integration disequilibrium and decide the time has
come to deal with it directly. We start hearing arguments that “this is what
will happen if we allow the European Union to be an à la carte menu, a
two-speed Europe, and so on”—the masses will try to pick and choose among the
things they want at that moment (yes to trade, no to immigration, for example)
and lose sight of the bigger purpose.
The truly consequential shift
would be the recognition that, since they have lost sight of it already, a new
and even bigger purpose needs to be articulated. More than thirty years ago,
Jacques Delors travelled around European capitals to assess appetites for a new
leap forward; the result was the single market and the road to the euro. This
generation’s Delors equivalent would have to find a much broader consensus on a
much bigger stage. The obvious target remains a fiscal union that could
credibly generate a commitment to massive fiscal stimulus now and appropriate
retrenchment, with debt repayment and budget surpluses, in the future.
Could a political entrepreneur
put this package together and sell it to a smaller core group, perhaps the
founding members of European integration, with France and Germany at the core?
It’s not impossible. But if it were to happen, it would almost by necessity
leave the rest of the European Union to fade backward into something like a
free trade zone. And the core would become something more like a new superstate
than an international organization.
In The Globalization
Paradox, Dani Rodrik described a trilemma of global integration,
nation-state sovereignty, and democracy; you can have two of the three at the
same time, but not all three.9 He was basically right, but a new EU core could
consciously choose to redefine its endpoint as a new nation-state. The problem
is, the past two decades of European integration were spent running away from
that conscious re-definition.
The more likely path forward
looks something like this. A Euro-Gorbachev figure emerges in the wake of
Brexit, with her own program of restructuring/perestroika to renew EU
institutions. She might be a young MEP from one of the new Eastern member
states, or a prominent national politician from France or Germany; she is
unlikely to be found today in Brussels. She certainly won’t use the word
perestroika as she goes about convincing others that her institutional reform
package can save the European Union. But the media will use that word, with
justification and unknowing irony.
If the foregoing analysis is
correct, we expect that European Union perestroika will fail for the same
reasons that Gorbachev’s version did. The institutions of the European Union
are too complex, too interconnected, too insulated, too rigid, and ultimately
too self-absorbed to grasp the necessity for change. The Eurocrats who run
them, like Brezhnev’s nomenklatura, might be holding on to that last little bit
of utopian thinking or they might just be holding on to their comfortable
sinecures—but in either case they will fight perestroika tooth and nail in
every possible under-the-table manner of blocking, foot-dragging, and
obfuscation. Some national political leaders might join the call. But likely
not the ones who matter most in France and Germany, as their ambivalence about
supranational governance will ultimately lead them to favor intergovernmental
deals that mostly bypass Brussels.
We give the perestroika campaign about three
years before its proponents recognize that they have to up the ante and move on
to their own version of social media-enabled glasnost.
In the European context,
“open-ness” will take the form of an appeal to mass national populations, over
the heads of their leadership. Citizens will be called on to rescue the
European Union. They will be told that it is essential to peace on the
continent. They will be told that only at the supranational level can Europe
fashion a plausible political and economic response to globalization. They will
probably be told that Brussels is the only place where regulators can stand up
to the cultural and privacy penetration of European societies by American
internet giants (the GAFA coalition10) and everything, especially the “social dumping,”
they represent.
Ultimately, the European
glasnost appeal will have to point backward to the utopian vision of European
integration that launched the project to gain any chance of credibility.
Gorbachev tried to do the same in his context. What he discovered was that the
population not only didn’t believe it anymore, they scoffed at it. When Soviet
citizens were given the chance to say no to official political candidates for
the first time in seventy years, they said no in almost all the major cities throughout
the USSR. In the EU context it might be the populations of new member states
that say no. It might be the populations of Italy, or France, or perhaps even
Germany that say no. It might be all of these. But there will be sufficient
refusals to sap whatever legitimacy is left from EU institutions. At that
point, the emergence of a Yeltsin-type entrepreneur who sees the opportunity in
the politics of break-up becomes almost inevitable.
After the Soviet Union
collapsed, most of the constituent republics came back together loosely in
something called the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS). It was just
enough of a political umbrella to give cover to de facto independence—a few
meetings a year, some broad “shared” economic goals, and a small bureaucracy
that was mainly responsible for propaganda.
Europe on the other side of
the European Union will probably do better than that, but maybe not all that
much better. The European Union may end, as do the plans of all hollow men, not
with a bang but a whimper.
Nils Gilman is an
historian and associate chancellor at the University of California, Berkeley.
Steven Weber is professor at the School of Information and Department of
Political Science, University of California, Berkeley.
No comments:
Post a Comment