What Japan’s economic experiment can teach the rest of the world
IN THE 1980s Japan was a closely studied example of
economic dynamism. In the decades since, it has commanded attention largely for
its economic stagnation. After years of falling prices and fitful growth,
Japan’s nominal GDP was roughly the same in 2015 as it was 20 years earlier.
America’s grew by 134% in the same time period; even Italy’s went up by
two-thirds. Now Japan is in the spotlight for a different reason: its attempts
at economic resuscitation.
To reflate Japan and
reform it, Shinzo Abe, prime minister since December 2012, proposed the three
“arrows” of what has become known as Abenomics: monetary stimulus, fiscal
“flexibility” and structural reform. The first arrow would mobilise Japan’s
productive powers and the third would expand them, allowing the second arrow to
hit an ambitious fiscal target. The prevailing view is that none has hit home.
Headline inflation was negative in the year to May. Japan’s public debt looks
as bad as ever. In areas such as labour-market reform, nowhere near enough has
been done.
Compared with its own grand promises, Abenomics has
indeed been a disappointment. But compared with what preceded it, it deserves a
sympathetic hearing (see article). And as
a guide to what other countries, particularly in Europe, should do to cope with
a greying population, stagnant demand and stubborn debts, Japan again repays
close attention.
This arrow points up
Take monetary policy.
The lesson many are quick to draw from Abenomics is that the weapons deployed
by the Bank of Japan (BoJ)—and, by extension, other central banks—since the
financial crisis do not work. The BoJ has more than doubled the size of its balance-sheet
since April 2013 and imposed a sub-zero interest rate in February; still more
easing may be on the way (the BoJ was meeting as The
Economistwent to press). Yet its
2% inflation target remains a distant dream.
The naysayers have it wrong. Unlike other countries,
Japan includes energy prices in its core inflation figure. Excluding them, core
consumer prices have risen, albeit modestly, for 32 months in a row. Before
Abenomics, Japan’s prices had fallen with few interruptions for over ten years;
they are now about 5% higher than they would have been had that trend
continued. Japan has increased inflation while it has fallen in Australia,
Britain, France, Germany, Italy and Spain.
If central banks have
more sway than some pundits allow, Abenomics also shows the limits of their
power. The BoJ has buoyed financial assets, but it has failed to drum up a
similar eagerness on the part of consumers or companies to buy real assets or
consumer goods. Household deposits are high. And despite bumper corporate profits,
firms doubt such plenty will persist. They have been happy to raise prices but
less eager to lift investment or base pay (which are harder to reverse).
Japan’s non-financial firms now hold more than ¥1 quadrillion ($9.5 trillion)
of financial assets, including cash.
Herein lies another
lesson of Abenomics: monetary policy is less powerful when corporate governance
is lax and competition muted. Mr Abe has handed shareholders greater power. In
2012 only 40% of leading companies had any independent directors; now nearly
all of them do. But if Japan’s equity culture were more assertive still,
shareholders might demand more of the corporate cash hoard back—to spend or
invest elsewhere. And if barriers to entry were lower, rival firms might expand
into newly profitable industries and compete away these riches. They might also
pay more. In theory, reflating an economy should be relatively popular, because
wage rises should precede price increases. In reality, the price rises came
first and pay has lagged behind. That is why the IMF has pushed for Japan to
adopt an incomes policy that spurs firms to raise wages.
Someone must spend
If companies are
determined to spend far less than they earn, some other part of the economy
will be forced to do the opposite. In Japan that role has fallen to the
government, which has run budget deficits for over 20 years. Mr Abe set out
intending to rein in the public finances. But after a rise in a consumption tax
in 2014 tipped Japan into recession, he has backed away from raising the tax
again. This week he signalled a large new fiscal-stimulus package worth ¥28
trillion, or 6% of GDP (although it was unclear how much of that money will be
new).
Abenomics has not only
demonstrated how self-defeating fiscal austerity can be, particularly when it
comes in the form of a tax on all consumers. It has also shown that, in
Japanese conditions, sustained fiscal expansion is affordable. Without any
private borrowers to crowd out, even a government as indebted as Japan’s will
find it cheap to borrow. Japan’s net interest payments, as a share of GDP, are
still the lowest in the G7. Politicians in Europe make fiscal rectitude a
priority. Abenomics shows that public thrift and private austerity do not mix.
Many people argue that
Mr Abe’s monetary and fiscal stimulus has served only as an analgesic, masking
the need for radical structural reform. To be sure, greater boldness is
needed—to encourage more foreign workers into the country, for example, and to
enable firms to hire and fire more easily. But a revival in demand has
encouraged supply-side improvement, not simply substituted for it. Stronger
demand for labour has drawn more people into the workforce, despite the decline
in Japan’s working-age population. The increased presence of women in the
labour force has prompted the government to create 200,000 extra places in
nurseries, and to make life harder for employers who discriminate against
pregnant employees. In recognising that reflation and reform go hand in hand,
Abenomics is an unusually coherent economic strategy.
Abenomics has fallen
short of its targets and its overblown rhetoric. That makes it easy to dismiss
as a failure. In fact, it has shown that central banks and governments do have
the capacity to stir a torpid economy. And in some senses, the hype was needed.
Japan’s stagnation had become a self-fulfilling prophecy; Abenomics could
succeed only if enough people believed it would. This is a final lesson that
Japan’s economic experiment can impart to the rest of the world. Aim
high.
No comments:
Post a Comment