by Matthew McManus
The defence of capitalism as a system of
economic organization often takes the form of strangely pious declarations
about how we have strayed from the path. This could involve over taxation,
limiting incentives, government takeovers of industry. Crises, it is claimed,
emerge from our failure to allow the market to work its miraculous power
divorced from the interfering hand of government and social sentiment which
produces inefficient and unjust distributions of wealth, followed by gluts
which result in inflation, crises and depression.
Oddly, it was the great libertarian economist,
Hayek himself, who formulated the most concise internal rejoinder to such
idealizations. As a Darwinian epistemologically, he understood better than
most that the market system that now dominates our world had emerged as
a result of contingent and circumstantial accidents around the Atlantic.
While he felt that it was the most rational system to allocate goods, he had no doubt that the proclivity towards over consumption and poor investment would lead to crises which government interference could only make worse. He was far more clear minded than the later monetarists, such as Friedman and Sowell, who always envision a utopia yet to be divorced from history and contingency, in which the rationalizing power of the invisible hand will distribute wealth in a manner both efficient and in line with the principles of classical liberal justice.
While he felt that it was the most rational system to allocate goods, he had no doubt that the proclivity towards over consumption and poor investment would lead to crises which government interference could only make worse. He was far more clear minded than the later monetarists, such as Friedman and Sowell, who always envision a utopia yet to be divorced from history and contingency, in which the rationalizing power of the invisible hand will distribute wealth in a manner both efficient and in line with the principles of classical liberal justice.
They do not recognize that their utopias are just that;
fantasies with little grounding in either history or economic reality. The
failings of capitalism, like its successes, do not result from some bizarre
unwillingness to let the market work its distributive magic. They are precisely
what they appear in material fact; the failings and successes of capitalism
within the world of actual human beings who are forced to live within time
rather than divorced from it. This complex relationship with time is among the
defining features of capitalism and help us account for its benefits and
limitations in a less abstract way than is typically found in micro-economic
modelling. One of its most tense limitations are the ways through which
capitalism produces a culture centered around individuals who must lack
individuality.
Capitalism tries to evade individuality through
the production and expansion of difference along the lines directed and limited
by capital. Saying that, I do not wish to deny its accomplishments for
improving the lot of many; but merely to point out that its limitations are
modes through which we think and act and not conditions in which we are bound
to exist. Our responsibility is to always overcome limitations; as such,
capitalism should one day be replaced by a more egalitarian system of
distribution that I will sketch out later in this piece. Saying that, my
normative critique is fused with an institutional analysis. For it is in no
small part through the constraints it places upon human expression that
capitalism finds itself in spiralling cycles of overconsumption, gluts,
inflation, depression, and recovery. This, or so I argue, will remain
unchanged so long as we remain human beings with the capacity to achieve more.
Capitalism as an economic system is
a chimera; continually choking on its own accomplishments as it seeks to
satisfy a never ending hunger for producing new values. Along this line,
its three greatest analysts were Marx, Keynes and Schumpeter. Each understood
that the inherent tensions produced by capital expansion were directly
responsible for its crises and redemption, each following smoothly in
succession within a strictly delineated time.
I characterize time as delineated for capitalism
not to raise a new theoretical problem about temporality but to point out
the inherent manner in which the ecstatic experience of human life within time
needs to be evaded and reduced down to moments of desire and consumption which
allow the system to function on a day to day basis leading to aggregate
gains for competitive firms. This leads to the crises of capitalism, as the
futural projections of individual firms come into conflict with their immediate
needs as retailers in the present. This Keynes understood better than anyone
else. His General Theory of Employment, Interest and Moneyis
a terribly written book, but one that truly understood and articulated the
nature of time in capitalist society. Its break with the classical paradigm lay
not in its proposition that the government could play a role in improving
the economy. This was an incidental contribution. It is the founding text of
macroeconomics because it recognized that the expectations of firms and their
inability to accommodate the future were what was responsible for the cyclical
woes of the system.
But this puts firms in a difficult
situation, since they must always produce the values of tomorrow to compete
with those of today. But capitalism demands that both firms and consumers not
think of tomorrow as an actual historical event but rather as merely another
moment in the clockwork process of labour and consumption. Despite all the
emphasis placed on saving, there is no sense in which this is seen as
a good in and of itself but only as a prerequisite for greater
returns and consumption at a later date. The propensity for
underconsumption promoted by mercantilism has been decisively destroyed. When
significant funds of money are hoarded it is only during crisis periods which
further exacerbates the problems of decreasing liquidity, minimal investment
and inflation.
Capitalism must always demand that consumers
subordinate the future to the interests of the present, even when the products
being marketed are to be consumed in the future. These problems with time lead
to overconsumption which cannot be supported by consumers of the present, who
are always milked beyond their capacity to give, necessitating temporary credit
solutions that postpone the day of reckoning to a point where crisis
becomes catastrophe. When this happens we see the collapse of old values and
the creation of new ones; the process of creative destruction upon which
capital relies for its dynamism while simultaneously dreading its consequences
at the level of individual firms and their employees who are condemned to fall
and rise as the system re-establishes the status quo and the whole process
begins again.
Throughout all this, difference is produced via the production of
new values which exist in conflict with one another in the market which simultaneously
validates and alienates them by not allowing them free reign beyond the
boundaries established by capital. In this sense, Marx was entirely right to
claim that the limits of capital are capital itself.
Marx did not commence Capital with
an account of the commodity by coincidence. The commodity simultaneously
expresses the allure and ultimate failure of capitalism as a stable and
empowered form of economic organization. Beyond their use value, commodities
are associated with the expression of individuality that codes the subject
according to their commercial preferences. In modern societies, this takes the
form of consumption for the purposes of manifesting a present divorced
from the impact of real history. When I consume a product, it is
intended not just to gratify a desire, but to sublimate it as a part
of my identity; that part which can be given expression in the public world
with dignity because it is undertaken along the lines commended and authorized
by capital. Cars, homes, plants, diets, gym memberships, and social media are
all part of this same process of making present what seems absent; an identity
that is always to come.
But the needs of capital require that this promise of
a present identity given social expression never arrives, since this would
cease the process of fetishization and consumption. It is always what leads so
many of its theoretical proponents by necessity to embrace the defence of
capitalism that requires the desires which produce demand be stripped of
a rich temporal dimension and reduced to a bizarre idealism which
takes the cognitive aspect of desire as it is in order to draw the positivists’
conclusion that it must be organized in a rational system which enables
the maximization of wealth so that consumers can make a broader range of
individual choices about which commodities they wish to acquire.
These choices,
in a fully capitalist society stripped of historical diversity, are not to
be questioned except to the degree that they might interfere with the
operations of capital itself. By presenting desire as something not to be
questioned but exclusively fulfilled, capitalism reduces history down to
a present where the primary drive is a superficially objective
association with the commodity.
In such a system, identity can never become
authentic, but needs to develop ahistorically since the different identifiers
associated with objects cannot become fixed and united or the consumption
process itself would cease. Capitalism is tied to the production of new values
which are mutually constitutive of the desires they seek to meet. Because of
this, old commodities begin to lose marginal utility and are usually re-assimilated
by competitive firms or else fade from the market. This is the process
Schumpeter characterized as creative destruction; the process through which
capitalism destroys old values to repackage or create new ones.
The sorry rise and fall of commodities, from the
beaver pelt top hat to the music industry, could be perpetuated indefinitely
and history put on hold if it weren’t for the consequences of capital
accumulation which gradually (though with accelerating pace in a neo-liberal
political system) pushes wealth into the hands of monopolizing firms. They
could potentially invest this profit as new capital, but it is instead
funnelled into the financial market decreasing the overall liquidity of actual
money while increasing the need for credit. As Weber claimed, this is the
tension that emerges in all large scale firms; officials with significant
control are not always best served by re-investment and so instead appropriate
funds for their private needs. This, of course, is an entirely “rational”
gesture for private actors who after all need fear no reprisals since they are
protected by the sanctity of private property.
No comments:
Post a Comment